Book cover of Economics: The User’s Guide by Ha-Joon Chang

Economics: The User’s Guide

by Ha-Joon Chang

22 min readRating: 4.2 (7,795 ratings)
Genres
Buy full book on Amazon

Introduction

Economics is often viewed as a dry, complex subject filled with confusing jargon and abstract theories. However, in "Economics: The User's Guide," Ha-Joon Chang presents a refreshingly accessible and engaging exploration of this crucial field that shapes our daily lives in countless ways. This book serves as an invaluable primer for anyone seeking to understand the foundations of economic theory and its real-world applications.

Chang takes readers on a journey through the history and evolution of economic thought, explaining key concepts and schools of thought in clear, simple language. He examines how our modern capitalist system came to be and how it continues to change in response to global events and technological advancements. Throughout the book, Chang challenges conventional wisdom and encourages readers to think critically about economic policies and their impacts on society.

The Scope and Importance of Economics

Economics is far more than just a collection of dry statistics and mathematical models. It is a field that touches every aspect of our lives, from the clothes we wear to the food we eat and the jobs we hold. Chang emphasizes that while economic theories can be applied to various situations, their most important application is in studying and understanding the economy itself.

At its core, economics is about how society manages its scarce resources to produce goods and services and distribute them among its members. It examines the complex web of relationships between producers, consumers, workers, and governments, all of which play crucial roles in shaping our economic landscape.

One of the fundamental concepts in economics is money, which serves as a measure of what society owes individuals for their contributions, typically through labor. Money facilitates the exchange of goods and services and can be transferred between individuals and groups through various mechanisms, such as welfare systems.

Chang also introduces the concept of production, which involves the combination of labor (workers) and capital (machines and tools) to create goods and services. This process is at the heart of economic activity and helps explain how our modern world of abundant consumer goods and advanced technologies came to be.

The Evolution of Capitalism

To understand our current economic system, it's essential to examine how capitalism has evolved over time. Chang takes readers on a historical journey, contrasting the economic landscape of the past with the globalized world we live in today.

In the 18th century, Scottish economist Adam Smith laid the groundwork for modern capitalist theory in his influential work, "An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations." Smith introduced the concept of the "invisible hand" of the market, arguing that individuals pursuing their self-interest would ultimately benefit society as a whole. He also emphasized the importance of the division of labor in increasing productivity, using the example of pin manufacturing to illustrate how specialization could dramatically boost output.

However, the economic world of Smith's time was vastly different from our own. Businesses were typically owned by individuals directly involved in production, such as village blacksmiths or butchers. Markets were largely regional or national at best, and companies were generally small in scale.

Fast forward to today, and we see a radically transformed economic landscape. Many companies are now owned by numerous shareholders who have little to no involvement in day-to-day operations. Globalization has created truly international markets, allowing for the rise of massive multinational corporations that wield enormous economic power.

This shift has brought both benefits and challenges. On one hand, it has led to unprecedented levels of productivity and access to a wide range of goods and services. On the other hand, it has raised concerns about income inequality, corporate responsibility, and the concentration of economic power in the hands of a few global players.

Historical Forces Shaping Our Economic System

Chang highlights several key historical events and policies that have played crucial roles in shaping our current economic system. One such factor was the trade policies of powerful Western nations during the Industrial Revolution in the late 18th and early 19th centuries.

Countries like the United States and the United Kingdom implemented protectionist policies, using tariffs to shield their domestic industries from foreign competition. This allowed their nascent industries to grow and thrive without being overwhelmed by more established foreign producers. At the same time, these Western powers often forced countries in Latin America and Asia into free-trade agreements, opening up these markets to highly competitive Western products.

This imbalance in trade policy helped cement the economic dominance of Western nations, creating a divide between developed and developing economies that persists to this day. It's a stark reminder that the current global economic order is not simply the result of natural market forces, but has been shaped by deliberate policy choices and historical power dynamics.

Another pivotal moment in economic history was the Great Depression of the 1930s. The stock market crash of 1929 and the subsequent economic collapse led to widespread unemployment, poverty, and social upheaval. This crisis shook the foundations of economic thought and prompted governments to take a more active role in managing their economies.

In response to the Great Depression, many countries implemented new social welfare programs and economic regulations. The United States, for example, introduced the Social Security Act in 1935, providing old-age pensions and unemployment insurance. These measures marked a significant shift towards greater government involvement in the economy, aimed at providing a safety net for citizens and stabilizing economic fluctuations.

Schools of Economic Thought

Chang provides an overview of the major schools of economic thought, helping readers understand the different perspectives that shape economic policy debates. He focuses particularly on two influential schools: the Neoclassical School and the Keynesian School.

The Neoclassical School, which emerged in the 1870s, is the dominant paradigm in modern economics. It builds on classical economic ideas but introduces new concepts and analytical tools. Key principles of neoclassical economics include:

  1. Economic actors (individuals and firms) are driven by self-interest and make rational choices to maximize their utility or profit.
  2. Markets are generally self-equilibrating and efficient, meaning they can adjust to shocks and allocate resources optimally without much external intervention.
  3. The value of a product depends on both its production cost and its perceived value to consumers (subjective theory of value).

Neoclassical economists generally advocate for limited government intervention in the economy, arguing that free markets will produce the best outcomes in most cases.

The Keynesian School, named after British economist John Maynard Keynes, emerged in response to the Great Depression. Keynesian economics challenges some of the core assumptions of neoclassical theory, particularly the idea that markets are always self-equilibrating. Key Keynesian ideas include:

  1. Aggregate demand (total spending in the economy) is the primary driver of economic activity.
  2. During economic downturns, people tend to save more and spend less, which can lead to a vicious cycle of reduced spending, lower production, and increased unemployment.
  3. Government intervention, particularly through fiscal policy (government spending and taxation), can help stabilize the economy during recessions.

Keynesian economists argue that government should play an active role in managing the economy, especially during economic crises. They advocate for increased government spending during recessions to boost demand and create jobs.

Understanding these different schools of thought is crucial for making sense of economic policy debates. While neoclassical economics emphasizes the efficiency of free markets, Keynesian economics highlights the potential instability of market economies and the need for government intervention to ensure full employment and economic stability.

Measuring Economic Health

Chang explains that assessing a country's economic health involves looking at various indicators and measurements. Two key metrics are Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Gross Domestic Income (GDI).

GDP represents the total monetary value of all goods and services produced within a country's borders over a specific period, typically a year. It's calculated by adding up the value added at each stage of production. For example, if a bakery has $150,000 in revenue but spent $100,000 on ingredients, its contribution to GDP would be the added value of $50,000.

GDI, on the other hand, measures the total income earned by a country's residents. This includes wages, profits, rents, and other forms of income. In theory, GDP and GDI should be equal, as the income generated from production should match the value of that production.

However, Chang cautions that these measures have limitations. For instance, GDP doesn't account for the distribution of wealth within a country or the environmental costs of economic activity. Moreover, comparing GDI across countries can be misleading due to differences in the cost of living. To address this, economists use purchasing power parity (PPP) adjustments, which account for differences in the cost of goods and services between countries.

Chang also emphasizes that GDP growth alone doesn't tell the whole story of a country's economic development. He uses the example of Equatorial Guinea, which experienced rapid GDP growth due to oil discoveries but didn't see corresponding improvements in living standards for most of its population. Instead, Chang argues that we should focus on economic development, which involves increases in a country's productive capabilities and improvements in living standards.

One indicator of economic development is the share of investment in GDP. When companies invest in fixed capital (like machines and infrastructure), it can lead to increased productivity and long-term economic growth. For example, investing in advanced manufacturing technologies like computer numerical control (CNC) machines can significantly boost a company's production capacity and efficiency.

Inequality and Its Economic Impact

Chang dedicates significant attention to the issue of economic inequality, arguing that it's not just a moral concern but also has important economic implications. He notes that the pursuit of equality is a fundamental human instinct, as evidenced by historical events like the French Revolution with its rallying cry of "Liberty, equality, fraternity or death."

Inequality can have several negative effects on an economy:

  1. Political and social instability: High levels of inequality can lead to social unrest and political instability, which can deter investment. Chang contrasts the investment levels in stable Austria ($10 billion in 2011) with those in unstable Somalia ($100 million in the same year) to illustrate this point.

  2. Limited social mobility: When wealth is concentrated among a small elite, it becomes harder for individuals from less privileged backgrounds to access opportunities for advancement. This can lead to a waste of human potential and reduce overall economic dynamism.

  3. Reduced consumer demand: As wealth becomes concentrated at the top, overall consumer spending may decrease, as the wealthy tend to save a higher proportion of their income compared to middle and lower-income groups.

Chang introduces the Gini coefficient as a way to measure income inequality. This metric ranges from 0 (perfect equality, where everyone has the same income) to 1 (perfect inequality, where one person has all the income). Most developed countries have Gini coefficients between 0.3 and 0.5, with higher values indicating greater inequality.

Understanding and addressing inequality is crucial for creating a healthy, sustainable economy. Chang argues that some level of inequality can provide incentives for hard work and innovation, but excessive inequality can be harmful to economic growth and social cohesion.

Government's Role in the Economy

Despite the prevalence of free-market ideology, Chang explains that governments play a crucial role in shaping and managing modern economies. He outlines several areas where government intervention is necessary or beneficial:

  1. Public goods: Some essential services and infrastructure, like roads, national defense, or public health systems, are not efficiently provided by the free market alone. Governments step in to ensure these public goods are available to all citizens.

  2. Regulation of natural monopolies: In industries where competition is naturally limited (like utilities or public transportation), government regulation can prevent abuse of monopoly power and ensure fair pricing.

  3. Taxation: Governments need to raise funds to provide public services and infrastructure. Taxation also serves as a tool for redistribution and can influence economic behavior.

  4. Macroeconomic management: Governments use fiscal and monetary policies to stabilize the economy, promote growth, and control inflation.

Chang describes two main tools governments use to influence the economy:

  1. Fiscal policy: This involves adjusting government spending and taxation levels. For example, increasing public spending on infrastructure projects during a recession can create jobs and stimulate economic activity.

  2. Monetary policy: Central banks, acting on behalf of the government, can adjust interest rates and the money supply to influence economic conditions. Lower interest rates, for instance, can encourage borrowing and investment.

The appropriate level of government intervention in the economy is a subject of ongoing debate among economists and policymakers. While some argue for a minimal state role, Chang suggests that judicious government action can help create a more stable and prosperous economy.

The Financial Sector and Its Evolution

Chang devotes considerable attention to the financial sector, which has grown increasingly complex and influential in recent decades. He distinguishes between two types of banks:

  1. Commercial or deposit banks: These are the banks most people interact with directly, offering services like checking and savings accounts, personal loans, and mortgages.

  2. Investment banks: Traditionally, these institutions helped companies raise capital from investors. However, since the 1980s, they've increasingly focused on creating and trading complex financial products.

Chang explains how the evolution of the financial sector, particularly the rise of complex financial instruments, played a significant role in the 2008 financial crisis. He uses the example of asset-backed securities (ABS) to illustrate this point.

ABSs are created by pooling many individual loans (like mortgages or student loans) into a single security that can be sold to investors. In theory, this diversification should make these securities safer. However, in practice, many ABSs were overvalued and riskier than believed, leading to massive losses when the housing market collapsed.

This example highlights the potential dangers of financial innovation when not properly understood or regulated. Chang argues that while financial services play a crucial role in modern economies, the sector's increasing complexity and size relative to the "real" economy (which produces goods and services) can pose significant risks.

Employment and Unemployment

Work is a central aspect of most people's lives, and Chang explores how our relationship with work has changed over time. He notes that while we may feel overworked today, we actually work far fewer hours than our ancestors did. In the 19th century, it was common for people to work 70-80 hours per week, compared to the 35-40 hours that are typical in many developed countries today.

Despite this reduction in working hours, our jobs still have a profound impact on our well-being, both physical and psychological. Some jobs carry physical risks, while others can be mentally stressful. Job satisfaction (or lack thereof) can significantly affect our overall happiness and quality of life.

Chang then turns to the issue of unemployment, which he categorizes into three main types:

  1. Frictional unemployment: This is the temporary unemployment that occurs when people are between jobs, either due to layoffs or voluntarily leaving to seek better opportunities.

  2. Technological unemployment: This happens when new technologies make certain jobs obsolete. While this has been a concern since the Industrial Revolution, economies have generally created new jobs to replace those lost to automation.

  3. Cyclical unemployment: This type of unemployment is caused by economic downturns, when overall demand for goods and services (and thus labor) decreases.

Understanding these different types of unemployment is crucial for developing effective policies to address joblessness. For example, programs to retrain workers might be effective in addressing technological unemployment, while government stimulus spending could help combat cyclical unemployment.

Chang also discusses the psychological impact of unemployment, noting that it can be one of the most stressful experiences in a person's life. This underscores the importance of not just creating jobs, but also ensuring that workers have protections and support systems in place.

Corporate Decision Making and Stakeholders

In contrast to individual economic decisions, corporate decision-making is often a complex process involving multiple stakeholders. Chang explains that unlike a person deciding to buy a car or a house, companies must balance the interests of various groups:

  1. Shareholders: As owners of the company, shareholders are interested in maximizing profits and increasing the value of their shares. However, in most large companies, individual shareholders rarely have enough voting power to control decisions directly.

  2. Managers: The executives who run the day-to-day operations of a company often have different priorities than shareholders. They might be more concerned with growing the size of the company (which can increase their prestige and compensation) rather than maximizing profitability.

  3. Workers: Employees, especially when organized into labor unions, can influence corporate decisions regarding wages, working conditions, and job security.

  4. Government: In some cases, governments may own shares in companies or have regulatory power that affects corporate decision-making.

Chang uses examples to illustrate these dynamics. For instance, he mentions the Wallenberg family in Sweden, which owns a significant stake in Saab, giving them substantial influence over the company's direction. He also notes that the German government holds a 25% stake in Commerzbank, allowing it to have a say in the bank's decisions.

These various stakeholders often have conflicting interests. Shareholders might push for cost-cutting measures to increase profits, while workers advocate for higher wages and better benefits. Managers might pursue growth strategies that don't necessarily maximize short-term profits but enhance their own status and job security.

Understanding these dynamics is crucial for comprehending how businesses operate and make decisions in the real world. It also highlights the complexity of corporate governance and the challenges of aligning the interests of various stakeholders.

International Trade and Globalization

Chang dedicates significant attention to the growing importance of international trade in the global economy. He notes that over the past 50 years, international trade has grown dramatically as a share of global economic activity. In the early 1960s, trade between countries accounted for about 12% of global GDP. By 2010, this figure had risen to 29%.

This increase in international trade has had profound effects on the structure of the global economy:

  1. Outsourcing: Many companies, especially in the technology sector, have moved services like customer support and software development to countries with lower wages.

  2. Global manufacturing: The manufacturing sector has become increasingly globalized, with complex supply chains spanning multiple countries. In 2010, manufacturing accounted for 69% of world merchandise trade.

  3. Rise of developing economies: International trade has allowed developing countries to play a larger role in the global economy. Chang uses China as an example, noting that its share of world manufacturing rose from just 0.8% in 1980 to 16.8% in 2012.

Chang also explains how countries finance their participation in international trade. When a country exports more than it imports, it generates a trade surplus. Conversely, a trade deficit occurs when imports exceed exports. Countries can finance trade deficits through various means:

  1. Investment income: Money earned from investments abroad, such as dividends from foreign stocks.

  2. Foreign aid: Grants provided by other governments or international organizations.

  3. Borrowing: Taking loans from foreign lenders or international institutions.

  4. Selling assets: This can include selling government bonds to foreign investors or allowing foreign companies to buy domestic assets.

Chang emphasizes that as globalization continues, understanding international trade dynamics becomes increasingly important for making sense of the world economy.

Financial Innovation and the 2008 Crisis

Chang provides an in-depth look at how financial innovation, particularly in the banking sector, contributed to the 2008 financial crisis. He explains that in recent decades, many banks have shifted their focus from traditional lending to creating and trading complex financial products.

One such product that played a significant role in the crisis was the asset-backed security (ABS). ABSs are created by pooling many individual loans, such as mortgages or student loans, into a single security that can be sold to investors. The idea behind ABSs was that by combining many loans, the risk would be spread out, making the overall security safer.

However, Chang points out that this theory had fatal flaws:

  1. Overvaluation: Many ABSs were given high ratings by credit agencies, suggesting they were very safe investments. In reality, many of the underlying loans were much riskier than believed.

  2. Complexity: The structure of these securities was often so complex that even many financial professionals didn't fully understand the risks involved.

  3. Misaligned incentives: The banks creating these securities often didn't hold onto them, instead selling them to other investors. This meant they had less incentive to ensure the quality of the underlying loans.

When the U.S. housing market began to decline and many homeowners started defaulting on their mortgages, the value of these securities plummeted. Banks that had invested heavily in ABSs and similar products faced huge losses, leading to a credit crunch that spread throughout the global financial system.

Chang argues that this crisis demonstrated the dangers of unchecked financial innovation and the need for better regulation of the financial sector. He suggests that while financial products can serve useful purposes, they need to be properly understood and their risks carefully managed to prevent future crises.

The Changing Nature of Work and Unemployment

Chang explores how the nature of work has evolved over time and the various factors that contribute to unemployment. He notes that while we often feel overworked in modern society, we actually work far fewer hours than our ancestors did. In the 19th century, it was common for people to work 70-80 hours per week, compared to the 35-40 hours that are typical in many developed countries today.

Despite this reduction in working hours, our jobs still have a profound impact on our well-being:

  1. Physical health: Some jobs, particularly in industries like construction or manufacturing, can be physically demanding and potentially hazardous.

  2. Mental health: Job satisfaction (or lack thereof) can significantly affect our overall happiness and quality of life.

  3. Work-life balance: The amount of time we spend at work affects our ability to engage in other activities and maintain relationships outside of work.

Chang then turns to the issue of unemployment, which he categorizes into three main types:

  1. Frictional unemployment: This is the temporary unemployment that occurs when people are between jobs, either due to layoffs or voluntarily leaving to seek better opportunities. Some level of frictional unemployment is normal and even necessary for a dynamic economy.

  2. Technological unemployment: This happens when new technologies make certain jobs obsolete. Chang notes that this has been a concern since the Industrial Revolution when machines began replacing manual labor in textile production. While technological change can eliminate some jobs, it typically creates new ones as well.

  3. Cyclical unemployment: This type of unemployment is caused by economic downturns, when overall demand for goods and services (and thus labor) decreases. The Great Depression of the 1930s is a classic example of severe cyclical unemployment.

Chang emphasizes that understanding these different types of unemployment is crucial for developing effective policies to address joblessness. For example:

  • Education and retraining programs can help address technological unemployment by equipping workers with new skills.
  • Government stimulus spending and monetary policy can help combat cyclical unemployment by boosting overall economic demand.
  • Improving labor market information and job search assistance can reduce frictional unemployment.

He also discusses the psychological impact of unemployment, noting that it can be one of the most stressful experiences in a person's life. This underscores the importance of not just creating jobs, but also ensuring that workers have protections and support systems in place.

Final Thoughts: The Importance of Economic Literacy

In concluding his comprehensive guide to economics, Chang emphasizes the critical importance of economic literacy in today's world. He argues that understanding basic economic concepts and being able to critically evaluate economic policies is essential for everyone, not just economists and policymakers.

Here's why economic literacy matters:

  1. Informed citizenship: Economic policies have a profound impact on our daily lives, from the prices we pay for goods to the availability of jobs. Being economically literate allows us to better understand and participate in democratic decision-making processes.

  2. Personal financial decisions: Understanding concepts like interest rates, inflation, and market dynamics can help individuals make better decisions about saving, investing, and managing their personal finances.

  3. Critical thinking: Economics provides tools for analyzing complex systems and trade-offs, skills that are valuable in many areas of life beyond just economic issues.

  4. Understanding global issues: Many of the world's most pressing challenges, from climate change to inequality, have significant economic dimensions. Economic literacy helps us grasp these issues more fully.

  5. Evaluating media and political claims: In an era of information overload, being able to critically assess economic claims and statistics is crucial for navigating public discourse.

Chang encourages readers to continue exploring economic ideas beyond this book. He suggests:

  • Reading a variety of economic perspectives, not just mainstream views.
  • Paying attention to economic news and trying to understand the underlying concepts.
  • Engaging in discussions about economic issues with others to gain different perspectives.
  • Applying economic thinking to everyday situations to practice these analytical skills.

By promoting economic literacy, Chang hopes to empower individuals to engage more effectively with the economic forces that shape our world. He believes that a more economically literate populace can lead to better policy decisions, more robust democratic participation, and ultimately, a fairer and more prosperous society for all.

In "Economics: The User's Guide," Ha-Joon Chang has provided readers with a comprehensive yet accessible introduction to the complex world of economics. By explaining key concepts, exploring different schools of thought, and examining real-world applications, Chang demystifies a subject that often seems intimidating to non-experts.

Throughout the book, Chang encourages readers to think critically about economic theories and policies, rather than accepting any single viewpoint as absolute truth. He emphasizes that economics is not just about abstract models and statistics, but about real people and their livelihoods.

By understanding the basics of how our economic system works, we can become more informed citizens, make better personal financial decisions, and contribute to discussions about the economic challenges facing our societies. In an increasingly interconnected and complex global economy, this knowledge is more valuable than ever.

Books like Economics: The User’s Guide