Book cover of The Curse of Bigness by Tim Wu

The Curse of Bigness

by Tim Wu

26 min readRating:4.2 (2,136 ratings)
Genres
Buy full book on Amazon

In "The Curse of Bigness," author Tim Wu explores the history and consequences of economic concentration, particularly the rise of monopolies and oligopolies. This book takes readers on a journey through the economic landscape of the United States, from the late 19th century to the present day, examining how the problem of economic concentration has evolved over time.

Wu argues that the concentration of economic power in the hands of a few giant corporations poses a significant threat to democracy, innovation, and fair competition. He traces the origins of this issue back to the Gilded Age, when industrial titans like John D. Rockefeller and J.P. Morgan built vast business empires that dominated entire industries. The book then follows the rise of the antitrust movement, which sought to break up these monopolies and restore competition to the marketplace.

As we'll see, the fight against economic concentration has been a long and complex one, with periods of progress followed by setbacks. Wu examines the arguments for and against monopolies, the legal battles that shaped antitrust policy, and the changing attitudes towards economic concentration over the decades.

Ultimately, "The Curse of Bigness" serves as a warning about the dangers of unchecked corporate power and a call to action for renewed efforts to promote competition and prevent the formation of new monopolies. With clear and engaging prose, Wu makes a compelling case for why this issue should matter to everyone, not just economists and policymakers.

Let's dive into the key ideas and historical developments that Wu presents in this important book.

The Rise of Economic Concentration in the Gilded Age

The Birth of the Trusts

The story of economic concentration in the United States begins in earnest during the Gilded Age, a period roughly spanning from the 1870s to 1900. This era was characterized by rapid industrialization, technological advancements, and the accumulation of vast wealth by a small group of industrialists and financiers.

During this time, the American economy underwent a dramatic transformation. Small, local businesses were increasingly replaced by large, national corporations. These corporations grew not just through organic expansion, but also through mergers and acquisitions. The result was the formation of "trusts" – massive business entities that controlled entire industries.

The scale of this consolidation was staggering. Between 1895 and 1904, approximately 2,274 manufacturing companies were merged into just 157 trusts. This wasn't just a matter of a few companies getting bigger – it represented a fundamental reshaping of the economic landscape.

Many of these trusts became dominant players in their respective industries. Out of the 93 major consolidations of the era, 72 of the resulting trusts captured market shares of more than 40 percent, and 42 of them reached more than 70 percent. This level of market dominance gave these trusts enormous power over prices, wages, and business practices within their industries.

The Rise of Monopolies

As the trusts grew larger and more powerful, some of them evolved into full-fledged monopolies. A monopoly occurs when a single company gains almost total control over an entire industry. By the early 1900s, monopolies had formed in nearly every major industry in the United States.

Some of the most famous monopolies of this era included:

  1. Standard Oil: Founded by John D. Rockefeller, Standard Oil dominated the oil industry, controlling everything from production to distribution.

  2. Carnegie Steel Company: Andrew Carnegie's company became the largest steel producer in the world, controlling a vast majority of steel production in the United States.

  3. American Tobacco Company: This trust controlled over 90% of the tobacco market in the US.

  4. AT&T: Under the leadership of Theodore Vail, AT&T established a monopoly over telephone services in the country.

The men behind these monopolies became some of the wealthiest individuals in history. John D. Rockefeller and Andrew Carnegie, for instance, amassed fortunes that would be worth over $300 billion each in today's dollars.

However, the most successful monopolist of the era was arguably J.P. Morgan. Unlike Rockefeller or Carnegie, who focused on single industries, Morgan achieved monopolies across a range of sectors. His empire included:

  • The Northern Securities Company (a railroad trust)
  • The International Mercantile Marine Co. (a shipping trust)
  • AT&T (a telecommunications trust)
  • US Steel (formed by merging hundreds of steel companies, including Carnegie Steel)

Morgan's approach exemplified the trend of the era: using financial power to consolidate entire industries under single corporate entities.

The Trust Movement and Its Ideology

As these monopolies grew in power and influence, a movement emerged to justify and promote their existence. This became known as the trust movement, and it was championed by figures like Rockefeller, Carnegie, and Morgan.

The trust movement put forward several arguments in favor of monopolies:

  1. Efficiency: They argued that large, centralized companies could operate more efficiently than multiple smaller competitors. This was based on the concept of economies of scale – the idea that production costs decrease as the scale of production increases.

  2. Stability: The trust movement claimed that monopolies brought stability to markets. They argued that competition led to chaos, with companies constantly struggling for survival at each other's expense. Monopolies, they said, could bring order and predictability to industries.

  3. Progress: Advocates of the trust movement saw monopolies as the next stage in the evolution of capitalism. They believed that by centralizing control of industries, monopolies could drive innovation and economic progress more effectively than a fragmented market of competing firms.

  4. Social Darwinism: Many in the trust movement subscribed to the idea of social Darwinism – the application of Charles Darwin's theory of evolution to social and economic contexts. They argued that monopolies were the natural result of economic "survival of the fittest," and that the companies that emerged as monopolies had proven themselves to be the most capable and efficient.

  5. Laissez-faire economics: The trust movement advocated for a hands-off approach from the government. They believed that the market should be allowed to operate without interference, even if that meant the formation of monopolies.

These arguments formed the ideological foundation for the trust movement and were used to justify the increasing concentration of economic power in the hands of a few large corporations.

The Dark Side of Monopolies

While the trust movement painted a rosy picture of monopolies as engines of progress and efficiency, the reality was often quite different. As monopolies grew in power and influence, their negative impacts on workers, consumers, and the broader economy became increasingly apparent.

Inefficiencies of Scale

One of the primary arguments in favor of monopolies was that they could achieve greater efficiency through economies of scale. However, Wu points out that when companies grow too large, they often begin to suffer from diseconomies of scale – becoming less efficient as they expand.

This inefficiency stems from several factors:

  1. Complexity: As companies grow larger, their operations become more complex. They require more employees, more managers, and more complicated hierarchies. This increased complexity can lead to bureaucratic inefficiencies and slower decision-making processes.

  2. Lack of adaptability: Larger companies tend to be less nimble and adaptable to changes in the market. With more moving parts, it becomes harder for these corporate giants to pivot quickly in response to new technologies, changing consumer preferences, or emerging competitors.

  3. Reduced innovation: Without the pressure of competition, monopolies may have less incentive to innovate and improve their products or services. This can lead to stagnation and a lack of progress in the industry.

Exploitation of Workers and Consumers

Perhaps the most significant downside of monopolies is their ability to exploit both workers and consumers due to their dominant market position.

For workers, the lack of competition in the job market means they have fewer options for employment within their industry. This allows monopolies to:

  1. Suppress wages: With no other major employers in the industry, workers have little leverage to negotiate for better pay.

  2. Impose harsh working conditions: Monopolies can enforce longer hours, reduce benefits, or maintain unsafe working environments with less fear of losing their workforce to competitors.

  3. Resist unionization: The concentration of power makes it easier for monopolies to resist workers' attempts to organize and bargain collectively.

Consumers also suffer under monopolies:

  1. Higher prices: Without competition, monopolies can raise prices with impunity, knowing that consumers have no alternative options.

  2. Reduced quality: The lack of competitive pressure may lead to a decrease in product or service quality over time.

  3. Limited choices: Monopolies can restrict the variety of products or services available to consumers, forcing them to accept whatever the company decides to offer.

Barriers to Entry and Competition

Monopolies don't just passively benefit from their dominant position – they actively work to maintain it by creating barriers to entry for potential competitors. Wu describes several tactics used by monopolies to prevent competition:

  1. Control of resources: Monopolies can secure exclusive access to necessary raw materials or infrastructure, making it impossible for new companies to enter the market.

  2. Predatory pricing: By temporarily lowering prices below cost, monopolies can drive smaller competitors out of business. Once the competition is eliminated, they can raise prices again.

  3. Exclusive deals: Monopolies can use their market power to force suppliers or distributors into exclusive arrangements, shutting out potential competitors.

  4. Regulatory capture: Using their financial and political influence, monopolies can shape regulations in ways that benefit them and disadvantage potential competitors.

An example of these tactics in action was John D. Rockefeller's Standard Oil. Rockefeller convinced railroads to give him special discounted rates for shipping oil while charging higher rates to his competitors. He also artificially lowered his prices to levels that smaller companies couldn't match, forcing them out of business or into selling their operations to Standard Oil.

Political Influence and Corruption

Perhaps the most insidious effect of monopolies is their ability to exert undue influence over the political process. With their vast financial resources and concentrated power, monopolies and oligopolies can shape government policy in ways that benefit them at the expense of the public interest.

Wu provides several examples of how this influence manifests:

  1. Lobbying: Large companies in concentrated industries can spend enormous sums on lobbying efforts to shape legislation in their favor.

  2. Campaign contributions: By donating to political campaigns, monopolies can gain access to and influence over elected officials.

  3. Revolving door: The movement of individuals between positions in the private sector and government can lead to regulatory decisions that favor large corporations.

  4. Threat of economic disruption: In some cases, monopolies become so integral to the economy that governments are reluctant to challenge them for fear of causing economic instability.

An example of this influence can be seen in the pharmaceutical industry. In 2013, pharmaceutical companies spent $116 million lobbying Congress to prohibit Medicare from negotiating lower drug prices. While this was a significant expenditure, it paled in comparison to the estimated $90 billion per year in additional revenue that the industry gained as a result.

Wu argues that this level of influence undermines democratic processes and leads to a system where the interests of large corporations often take precedence over the public good.

The Antitrust Movement and Government Response

Early Attempts at Regulation

As the negative impacts of monopolies and trusts became more apparent, public discontent began to grow. This led to the first attempts by the government to regulate and control the power of large corporations.

The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 was the first major piece of legislation aimed at combating monopolies. This law declared the formation of monopolies a felony and banned trusts or any other combination of companies that was "in restraint of trade."

However, the initial impact of the Sherman Act was limited. Many in the government, including President William McKinley (1897-1901), were reluctant to enforce the law aggressively. McKinley, who favored a laissez-faire economic policy, saw the act more as a symbolic gesture than a tool for active regulation.

The Rise of Trust-Busting

The tide began to turn with the assassination of McKinley in 1901 and the ascension of Theodore Roosevelt to the presidency. Roosevelt saw monopolies as a threat to democracy for two main reasons:

  1. Excessive power and influence: He believed that monopolies represented a form of private power that rivaled and threatened to overwhelm the public power of the state.

  2. Social unrest: Roosevelt feared that the economic hardships caused by monopolies could lead to social upheaval and potentially push people towards more extreme solutions, such as communism.

Under Roosevelt's leadership, the government began to actively pursue antitrust cases against major monopolies. His administration filed 45 antitrust lawsuits, targeting giants like J.P. Morgan's Northern Securities Company and Rockefeller's Standard Oil.

This trend continued under Roosevelt's successor, William Howard Taft, who filed another 75 antitrust cases. These efforts led to the breakup of several major monopolies, including:

  1. Standard Oil: In 1911, Standard Oil was broken into 34 separate companies, some of which remain major players in the oil industry today (e.g., Exxon, Mobil, Chevron).

  2. American Tobacco Company: Also in 1911, this monopoly was divided into several competing firms.

  3. Northern Securities Company: This railroad trust was dissolved in 1904.

The Clayton Antitrust Act and Federal Trade Commission

Building on the Sherman Act, Congress passed the Clayton Antitrust Act in 1914. This law strengthened antitrust regulations by:

  1. Prohibiting specific anticompetitive practices, such as price discrimination and exclusive dealing contracts.

  2. Exempting labor unions from antitrust laws, allowing workers to organize without fear of being accused of forming a "labor monopoly."

  3. Allowing private parties to sue for triple damages if they were harmed by conduct that violated antitrust laws.

In the same year, Congress also established the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). The FTC was given the authority to:

  1. Investigate potential antitrust violations
  2. Issue cease and desist orders against unfair methods of competition
  3. Enforce consumer protection laws

These new tools gave the government more power to prevent the formation of monopolies and to break up existing ones.

The Great Depression and World War II

The Great Depression of the 1930s temporarily shifted the government's focus away from antitrust enforcement. In fact, under President Franklin D. Roosevelt's New Deal, some antitrust laws were suspended in the hope that allowing greater cooperation between businesses would help stimulate the economy.

However, the experience of World War II reinforced the dangers of unchecked economic concentration. In Nazi Germany, powerful monopolies like IG Farben had become deeply intertwined with the fascist state, demonstrating the potential for concentrated economic power to support authoritarian regimes.

Post-War Antitrust Efforts

After World War II, the U.S. government renewed its commitment to antitrust enforcement with increased vigor. This was driven by several factors:

  1. Fear of fascism: The experience of Nazi Germany had shown how monopolies could support authoritarian regimes.

  2. Fear of communism: There was concern that if private monopolies became too powerful, it might lead to calls for nationalization of industries, as had happened in communist countries.

  3. Belief in competition: There was a strong belief that maintaining competitive markets was crucial for economic growth and innovation.

In 1950, Congress passed the Anti-Merger Act (also known as the Celler-Kefauver Act). This law gave the government more power to prevent mergers that could lead to monopolies, allowing regulators to address potential monopolies before they formed rather than having to break them up after the fact.

Throughout the 1950s, 1960s, and early 1970s, the government continued to pursue antitrust cases aggressively. This era saw the breakup of several major companies and the prevention of numerous mergers that were deemed anticompetitive.

The AT&T Case: A Landmark in Antitrust History

One of the most significant antitrust cases in U.S. history was the breakup of AT&T (American Telephone & Telegraph Company) in the 1980s. This case serves as a prime example of both the dangers of unchecked monopoly power and the potential benefits of antitrust action.

AT&T's Monopoly

AT&T, originally created by Alexander Graham Bell's Bell Telephone Company, had grown into a massive telecommunications monopoly by the 1970s. It was not just a monopoly, but what Wu calls a "super monopolist," controlling multiple related monopolies:

  1. Local telephone service
  2. Long-distance telephone service
  3. Physical telephones and accessories
  4. Telephone equipment manufacturing

The company's dominance was so complete that it was often referred to simply as "The Bell System" or "Ma Bell."

Regulated Monopoly?

In theory, AT&T was a regulated monopoly, with its operations subject to government oversight. However, the reality was often quite different. The company's relationship with regulators was so close that it often appeared as if AT&T was regulating the industry in its own interests, rather than being regulated by the government.

For example:

  1. Congress had made it illegal for companies to compete with AT&T in certain markets.
  2. The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) often helped AT&T quash even small competitors. For instance, the FCC prohibited other companies from selling answering machines that would attach to AT&T's phone lines.

The Antitrust Suit

In 1974, under the Nixon administration, the U.S. Department of Justice initiated an antitrust lawsuit against AT&T. The case dragged on for years, spanning multiple presidential administrations.

The government's case against AT&T included several key arguments:

  1. AT&T was using its monopoly in local telephone service to improperly exclude competitors in long-distance service and equipment manufacturing.
  2. The company was overcharging customers for certain services to subsidize others, distorting the market.
  3. AT&T was stifling innovation by preventing other companies from introducing new telecommunications products and services.

The Breakup

After years of legal battles, the case was settled in 1982 under the Reagan administration. The settlement, which took effect in 1984, required AT&T to divest its local telephone operations. This led to the creation of seven independent regional telephone companies, nicknamed the "Baby Bells."

The breakup had several key components:

  1. AT&T retained its long-distance service, equipment manufacturing (through Western Electric), and Bell Labs.
  2. The seven Baby Bells took over local telephone service in different regions of the country.
  3. The settlement opened up the long-distance market to competition.
  4. It also allowed other companies to sell telephone equipment that could connect to the telephone network.

The Aftermath

The breakup of AT&T had far-reaching consequences for the telecommunications industry and beyond:

  1. Increased competition: The breakup opened the door for new companies to enter the telecommunications market, leading to increased competition and innovation.

  2. Lower prices: Competition in long-distance service led to significantly lower prices for consumers.

  3. Innovation: The ability for other companies to connect equipment to the phone network spurred innovation in areas like answering machines, fax machines, and modems.

  4. Internet growth: The breakup indirectly contributed to the growth of the internet by allowing companies to offer online services over telephone lines.

  5. Mobile revolution: The more open and competitive environment helped pave the way for the mobile phone revolution.

The AT&T case stands as a powerful example of how antitrust action can foster competition, innovation, and consumer benefits. It demonstrated that even the largest and most entrenched monopolies could be successfully challenged and restructured for the public good.

The Decline of Antitrust Enforcement

The Chicago School and the Consumer Welfare Standard

Despite the success of the AT&T breakup, the late 20th century saw a significant shift in antitrust philosophy and enforcement. This change was largely driven by the rise of the Chicago School of economics and its influence on legal thinking.

The key figure in this shift was Robert Bork, a legal scholar who studied at the University of Chicago. In 1966, Bork published an influential paper titled "Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act." This paper proposed a radical reinterpretation of antitrust law:

  1. Consumer Welfare Focus: Bork argued that the sole aim of antitrust law should be to promote consumer welfare, narrowly defined in terms of lower prices.

  2. Efficiency Emphasis: He contended that many business practices previously seen as anticompetitive could actually increase economic efficiency and therefore benefit consumers.

  3. Skepticism of Government Intervention: Bork and his colleagues were generally skeptical of government intervention in markets, believing that markets would often correct themselves without need for antitrust action.

This approach, known as the "consumer welfare standard," gained popularity in law schools and courts throughout the 1980s and 1990s. It offered a seemingly simple and objective way to evaluate antitrust cases: if a business practice didn't lead to higher consumer prices, it wasn't anticompetitive.

The Impact on Antitrust Enforcement

The adoption of the consumer welfare standard had a profound impact on antitrust enforcement:

  1. Fewer Cases: The number of antitrust cases brought by the government declined dramatically.

  2. Higher Bar for Action: It became much harder to prove that a merger or business practice was anticompetitive, as long as it didn't immediately lead to higher prices.

  3. Shift in Focus: Antitrust enforcers became less concerned with market structure and concentration, focusing instead on specific anticompetitive behaviors.

  4. Permissive Approach to Mergers: Many mergers that would have been challenged in earlier decades were allowed to proceed.

This shift was exemplified by a 2004 Supreme Court decision, in which Justice Antonin Scalia wrote that monopoly pricing was "not only not unlawful," but an "important element of the free-market system," as it provided an incentive for innovation and economic growth.

The Microsoft Case: A Last Hurrah?

The antitrust case against Microsoft in the late 1990s seemed to buck this trend. The Department of Justice, along with 20 states, sued Microsoft for anticompetitive practices, particularly its bundling of Internet Explorer with Windows to dominate the web browser market.

Initially, the case seemed to be heading towards a major breakup of Microsoft. However, after George W. Bush became president in 2001, the Justice Department settled the case with much milder remedies. This settlement was seen by many as a disappointment and a sign of the weakening resolve for strong antitrust action.

The Return of Economic Concentration

As a result of this more permissive approach to antitrust enforcement, economic concentration began to increase across many sectors of the economy:

  1. Telecommunications: The breakup of AT&T was largely reversed, with many of the "Baby Bells" re-merging into large companies like Verizon and a reconstituted AT&T.

  2. Airlines: A series of mergers left just three major carriers dominating the U.S. market.

  3. Pharmaceuticals: The global pharmaceutical market consolidated from about 60 companies to just ten between 2005 and 2017.

  4. Technology: New tech giants like Google, Amazon, and Facebook emerged, often buying up potential competitors (e.g., Facebook's acquisitions of Instagram and WhatsApp).

  5. Media and Entertainment: Massive mergers created huge conglomerates controlling both content creation and distribution (e.g., Comcast's acquisition of NBCUniversal, Disney's purchase of 21st Century Fox).

This trend towards increased concentration has raised concerns about its impact on competition, innovation, and even democracy itself.

The Consequences of Renewed Economic Concentration

Impact on Consumers

The renewed concentration of economic power has had significant impacts on consumers:

  1. Higher Prices: In many industries, reduced competition has led to higher prices. For example, airline ticket prices have increased as the number of major carriers has decreased.

  2. Reduced Choice: Consolidation often leads to fewer options for consumers. This is particularly evident in industries like telecommunications, where many regions have only one or two choices for high-speed internet service.

  3. Diminished Quality: Without robust competition, companies may have less incentive to improve their products or services. This can lead to stagnation in quality or even a decline in customer service.

  4. Privacy Concerns: The dominance of tech giants like Google and Facebook has raised serious concerns about data privacy and the use of personal information for commercial purposes.

Impact on Workers

Economic concentration also affects workers:

  1. Wage Stagnation: With fewer employers competing for workers, companies may have less incentive to raise wages or improve benefits.

  2. Reduced Job Mobility: When a few large companies dominate an industry, workers may have fewer options to change jobs or negotiate better conditions.

  3. Weakened Bargaining Power: Large corporations often have more resources to resist unionization efforts or to outlast strikes.

Impact on Innovation

Contrary to arguments that large companies are better positioned to innovate, excessive concentration can actually stifle innovation:

  1. Reduced Competition: With less competitive pressure, dominant companies may have less incentive to innovate or improve their products.

  2. Barriers to Entry: Large incumbents can use their market power to prevent new, innovative companies from entering the market.

  3. Acquisition of Potential Competitors: Instead of competing with innovative startups, large companies often simply acquire them, potentially stifling the development of disruptive technologies.

Political Influence

Perhaps the most concerning consequence of economic concentration is its impact on the political process:

  1. Lobbying Power: Large corporations have vast resources to spend on lobbying efforts, potentially skewing legislation and regulation in their favor.

  2. Campaign Finance: The ability of corporations to make large political donations can give them outsized influence over elected officials.

  3. Regulatory Capture: Industries dominated by a few large players are often better positioned to influence the regulatory agencies meant to oversee them.

  4. Information Control: In the case of media and tech companies, their control over information flow can have significant implications for public discourse and democracy.

The Case for Renewed Antitrust Action

Given the negative consequences of economic concentration, Wu makes a strong case for reinvigorating antitrust enforcement. He proposes several approaches:

Broadening the Focus Beyond Consumer Welfare

Wu argues that antitrust enforcement should return to a broader understanding of its goals, moving beyond the narrow focus on consumer prices:

  1. Protecting Competition: The primary aim should be to maintain competitive markets, recognizing that competition itself is valuable even if it doesn't always lead to lower prices in the short term.

  2. Considering Worker Welfare: Antitrust analysis should consider the impact of mergers and business practices on workers, not just consumers.

  3. Protecting Innovation: Regulators should be more skeptical of mergers and practices that could stifle innovation, even if they don't immediately lead to higher prices.

  4. Preserving Economic Liberty: Wu argues that antitrust law should aim to preserve economic liberty by preventing excessive concentration of private power.

Strengthening Merger Review

Wu proposes several changes to how mergers are reviewed:

  1. Lowering Thresholds: The government should be more willing to challenge mergers that lead to high levels of market concentration, even if they don't create outright monopolies.

  2. Considering Potential Competition: Regulators should pay more attention to acquisitions of potential future competitors, particularly in fast-moving industries like technology.

  3. Post-Merger Review: There should be more robust review of past mergers to see if they've led to anticompetitive outcomes, with the possibility of breaking up companies if necessary.

Reinvigorating Monopoly Cases

Wu argues for a return to more aggressive pursuit of monopoly cases:

  1. Structural Remedies: When companies are found to have monopoly power, structural remedies (like breaking up the company) should be considered more often, rather than just behavioral remedies.

  2. Predatory Pricing: Antitrust enforcers should be more willing to challenge predatory pricing and other tactics used by dominant firms to maintain their market power.

  3. Essential Facilities Doctrine: Wu suggests reviving the "essential facilities" doctrine, which requires monopolists to provide access to critical infrastructure or resources to competitors under reasonable terms.

Addressing Tech Giants

Given the unique challenges posed by large tech companies, Wu proposes some specific approaches:

  1. Data Portability: Requiring companies to make user data portable and interoperable could reduce switching costs and foster competition.

  2. Limiting Vertical Integration: Regulators should be more skeptical of tech companies expanding into adjacent markets, potentially separating platforms from the services offered on them.

  3. Algorithm Transparency: There should be more scrutiny of the algorithms used by dominant tech platforms to ensure they're not unfairly favoring their own services.

Institutional Changes

Wu also suggests some institutional changes to strengthen antitrust enforcement:

  1. Increased Funding: Antitrust agencies need more resources to take on large, well-funded corporations.

  2. Political Independence: Antitrust enforcement should be insulated from political pressure as much as possible.

  3. Collaboration with Other Agencies: Antitrust enforcers should work more closely with other regulatory agencies (like the FCC or FTC) to address industry-specific issues.

Conclusion: The Importance of Antitrust in Preserving Democracy

In concluding "The Curse of Bigness," Tim Wu emphasizes the critical role that antitrust policy plays not just in economics, but in preserving democracy itself. He draws parallels between the current era of economic concentration and the Gilded Age, warning that we risk repeating the mistakes of the past if we don't take action.

Wu argues that excessive economic concentration leads to a concentration of political power, which can undermine democratic institutions. When a small number of large corporations dominate the economy, they can exert outsized influence over government policy, potentially leading to a form of corporate oligarchy.

Moreover, Wu contends that economic liberty – the ability of individuals to start businesses, compete fairly, and make economic choices without being dominated by overwhelming private power – is an essential component of political liberty. When economic power is too concentrated, it limits the economic freedom of individuals and small businesses, potentially stifling innovation, entrepreneurship, and economic mobility.

The author also emphasizes that the issue of economic concentration is not just a matter for economists or lawyers to debate. It has real, tangible impacts on people's daily lives – from the prices they pay for goods and services, to the wages they earn, to the choices available to them as consumers and workers.

Wu calls for a renewed commitment to the principles that motivated earlier antitrust efforts:

  1. A recognition that excessive private power can be as threatening to liberty as excessive government power.

  2. An understanding that competitive markets are not just about efficiency, but about fostering innovation, opportunity, and economic dynamism.

  3. A willingness to use government power to break up concentrations of private power when necessary.

He argues that by reinvigorating antitrust enforcement, we can help create a more dynamic, innovative, and equitable economy. This, in turn, can help preserve the economic liberty that is essential to political democracy.

Ultimately, "The Curse of Bigness" is a call to action. Wu urges policymakers, legal professionals, and citizens to recognize the dangers of unchecked economic concentration and to support efforts to restore competition to our markets. By doing so, he argues, we can help ensure that our economy serves the many, not just the few, and that our democracy remains vibrant and responsive to the needs of all citizens.

The book serves as a powerful reminder that antitrust is not just a technical legal or economic issue, but a fundamental question of what kind of society we want to live in. As we grapple with the challenges of the 21st century economy, Wu's insights provide a valuable roadmap for how we might create a more competitive, innovative, and democratic economic system.

Books like The Curse of Bigness