Book cover of The Shortest History of Economics by Andrew Leigh

The Shortest History of Economics

by Andrew Leigh

14 min readRating: 4.0 (302 ratings)
Genres
Buy full book on Amazon

Introduction

In "The Shortest History of Economics," Andrew Leigh takes readers on a captivating journey through the evolution of human economic systems. From the earliest days of our species to the complex global economy of today, this book explores the key innovations, ideas, and events that have shaped our economic world. Leigh's work offers a unique perspective on history, viewing pivotal moments through an economist's lens and explaining how these events continue to influence our modern economic landscape.

The Dawn of Economic Innovation

Our Hunter-Gatherer Origins

The story of human economics begins with our earliest ancestors. Homo sapiens emerged in southern Africa around 300,000 years ago, demonstrating remarkable innovation from the start. These early humans developed complex languages, created art, and organized into family units and larger tribal groups. By 65,000 years ago, they had invented tools like spears and bows for hunting, needles for sewing, and even basic boats for water travel.

For millennia, our ancestors lived a nomadic lifestyle, roaming vast territories in search of food. They hunted game and gathered local plants, moving on when resources in an area were depleted. This pattern of existence persisted for thousands of years, shaping the early history of our species and our relationship with the environment.

The Agricultural Revolution: A Economic Turning Point

The first major economic shift in human history occurred around 10,000 BCE with the advent of agriculture. This revolution marked a transition from nomadic hunter-gatherer societies to settled farming communities. The implications of this change were profound and far-reaching.

Agriculture introduced the concept of surplus production for the first time in human history. Communities could now produce more food than they immediately needed, opening the door to a revolutionary economic concept: consumption smoothing. Farmers could store food for lean times, effectively maintaining a more stable level of consumption despite seasonal fluctuations in production. This ability to smooth consumption helped ease the constant stress of food insecurity that had plagued our ancestors for hundreds of thousands of years.

However, the shift to agriculture wasn't without its drawbacks. Early farmers often suffered from less diverse diets compared to their hunter-gatherer predecessors. The higher population density in settled communities also increased vulnerability to diseases, introducing new health challenges.

Specialization and the Division of Labor

The ability to produce surplus food had another significant consequence: it allowed for specialization within communities. With not everyone needed for food production, some individuals could focus on developing other skills, such as toolmaking or pottery. This diversification of labor led to increased productivity and efficiency, as people could become experts in their chosen crafts.

Specialization also gave rise to trade, as people began to exchange their specialized goods and services with others. This exchange of goods and services formed the basis of early economic systems and laid the groundwork for more complex economic structures in the future.

The Emergence of Money

As trade expanded and became more complex, a new economic tool emerged: money. Money serves three primary functions in an economy:

  1. A unit of account: It provides a standard measure of value.
  2. A store of value: It allows wealth to be saved and used in the future.
  3. A medium of exchange: It facilitates transactions without the need for direct barter.

Early forms of money varied widely, from precious metals to carved stones. Each of these forms solved the problem of facilitating complex trades without requiring a direct match of bartered goods. The introduction of money made trade more efficient and allowed for more sophisticated economic interactions.

Comparative Advantage and Trade

As trade networks expanded, economies began to benefit from what economists call comparative advantage. This principle shows that mutually beneficial exchange is possible when each party focuses on producing what they're relatively better at, leading to greater overall productivity.

Comparative advantage explains why trade can be beneficial even when one party is more efficient at producing everything. By specializing in what they do best and trading for other goods, both parties can end up better off. This concept became a cornerstone of international trade theory and continues to shape global economic policies today.

The Printing Press: A Catalyst for Economic Growth

The invention of the printing press around 1440 marked another pivotal moment in economic history. Before this innovation, books were rare and expensive, each one painstakingly hand-copied by scribes over months. Owning a single book was a luxury reserved for the elite.

The printing press changed all that. It slashed the cost of book production dramatically. A book that once cost a year's wages now cost only a week's pay. This sudden flood of accessible knowledge had far-reaching consequences, catalyzing innovation across Europe and spurring economic growth in ways that would ripple through the centuries.

The printing press traded in a different kind of wealth: ideas. Unlike physical goods, ideas are what economists call "non-rival." If someone gives you an apple, they no longer have it – that's a rival good. But if someone teaches you a new skill, they still retain that skill themselves – that's non-rival. This concept of non-rivalry is crucial to understanding the economic impact of innovation.

As literacy rates soared due to the increased availability of books, more people could access and contribute to the growing pool of knowledge. Innovations in one field could spark breakthroughs in another, creating a virtuous cycle of progress and economic growth.

However, this explosion of ideas posed a new economic challenge: how to incentivize innovation while ensuring that knowledge spread. Venice's 1474 patent statute was a pioneering attempt to strike this balance, offering inventors temporary monopolies in exchange for sharing their ideas. This concept of intellectual property rights continues to be a crucial and often contentious aspect of modern economics.

Water Transport and Trade

While the printing press was revolutionizing the spread of ideas, water transport was reshaping trade in physical goods. Rivers and seas became highways of commerce, with coastal cities emerging as economic powerhouses.

China's Grand Canal, stretching over 1,600 kilometers, exemplified how waterways could knit together vast regions economically. In Europe, Venice flourished as a global trading hub, boasting a strategic location and innovative financial systems like the colleganza, a risk-sharing agreement for sea voyages. Lisbon's deep-water port made it a launchpad for explorers, while Alexandria's lighthouse guided ships laden with goods from across the known world.

These developments in water transport significantly reduced the costs of moving goods over long distances, enabling more extensive trade networks and fostering economic growth in coastal regions.

The Industrial Revolution: A New Economic Era

Before the Industrial Revolution, economic progress was slow. For centuries, growth crept along, gradually sustaining larger populations, but individual living standards remained largely stagnant. In the eighteenth century, however, all of that changed. A perfect storm of innovation began to sweep first across England and then the world, setting off a self-reinforcing cycle of progress.

This cycle worked like a vast, interconnected machine. Agricultural advancements freed up labor, fueling a boom in urban populations. Cities thus became crucibles of commerce and innovation, their dense networks sparking new ideas and enterprises. These innovations, in turn, drove further agricultural and industrial efficiency.

The invention of the steam engine provides a perfect example of this cycle. It led to more efficient mining, providing cheaper access to coal. This cheaper coal then powered more steam engines, which were used in factories, creating a positive feedback loop of industrialization and urbanization.

Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand

Amidst this period of rapid change, Adam Smith published his seminal work, "The Wealth of Nations." This book introduced the concept of the invisible hand, a metaphor describing how, in a free market, individual self-interest can lead – quite incidentally – to societal benefits.

Smith argued that when people pursue their own goals in a competitive market, they're inadvertently led to provide goods and services that others value, as if guided by an invisible hand. This insight helped explain how market economies could function to create wealth in a decentralized way, without the need for central planning.

John Stuart Mill's Contributions

John Stuart Mill further refined economic thought with two crucial concepts. His model of Homo economicus – portraying humans as rational, self-interested economic agents – became a cornerstone of economic analysis. While obviously a simplification, this model provided a useful framework for predicting economic behavior and designing policies.

Mill also introduced the idea of opportunity cost – the value of the next-best alternative that we forego when we make a decision. For example, the opportunity cost of attending university isn't just the tuition fees, but also the income you could have earned working full-time instead. This concept helps us understand the true cost of our choices in a world of scarcity.

The Dark Side of Industrialization

While the Industrial Revolution brought unprecedented economic growth, it also had a dark underbelly, manifested in urban poverty and harsh working conditions. The Poor Laws, dating back to Elizabethan times but amended in 1834, attempted to address these issues through a system of parish-based relief.

The workhouse system was a key part of this, providing food and shelter to the destitute in exchange for labor. However, conditions in workhouses were intentionally harsh to discourage all but the most desperate from seeking help, often leading to cruelty and counterproductive results.

Economic Upheaval and New Theories

World War I and Its Aftermath

World War I was perhaps the world's first fully industrialized war. It was a calamity, not just of human suffering and geopolitical upheaval, but in terms of setting the stage for profound economic turmoil. Its aftermath saw Germany burdened with crippling reparations, leading to hyperinflation, while the 1929 stock market crash ushered in the Great Depression, sending shockwaves through the global economy.

Keynes vs. Hayek: Competing Economic Philosophies

In response to this crisis, two competing economic philosophies emerged, shaping the discourse for decades to come. John Maynard Keynes advocated for active government intervention, arguing that increased public spending could stimulate economic recovery. He proposed that during downturns, governments should increase spending on public works and other programs to boost demand and employment.

Keynes likened the economy to a beehive, where one bee's thrift could lead to colony-wide misery – illustrating how individual actions can have unexpected collective consequences. His ideas formed the basis of much of modern macroeconomic policy.

In contrast, Friedrich von Hayek viewed recessions as necessary corrections for imprudent investments. He argued that artificially low interest rates led to poor investment decisions, and that allowing these investments to fail was a crucial part of economic renewal. Hayek saw government intervention as potentially harmful, delaying necessary adjustments and risking long-term economic distortions.

These divergent views reflected deeper philosophical differences. Keynes, the optimistic cosmopolitan, believed in the power of government to smooth economic cycles. Hayek, more austere and reserved, feared that government intervention could erode individual liberty and lead to unintended negative consequences.

National Income Accounting

Transforming economic analysis during this period was the development of national income accounting – a systematic approach to measuring a nation's economic output, income, and expenditure. Pioneers like Arthur Bowley, Colin Clark, and Simon Kuznets developed methods to calculate economic indicators like gross national product (GNP).

These tools enabled more accurate measurement of the nation's economic output, facilitating timely policy interventions and allowing for meaningful comparisons between countries and over time. The development of these economic indicators revolutionized the way governments and economists understood and managed national economies.

The Bretton Woods System

In the wake of World War II, the Bretton Woods Conference established a new international economic order. This system aimed to prevent the economic isolationism that had exacerbated the Great Depression. The World Bank and International Monetary Fund were created to provide institutional support for market-based international development and financial stability.

A modified gold standard was implemented, with the US dollar pegged to gold and other currencies pegged to the dollar, creating a framework for stable exchange rates. This new order promoted international trade and capital flows, laying the groundwork for the growth of post-war economies.

The Rise of Central Banks and Monetary Policy

In the latter half of the twentieth century, central banks emerged as key players in managing national economies. The specter of hyperinflation, which had ravaged countries like post-WWII Hungary, prompted policymakers to seek more flexible monetary tools. This led many nations to abandon the rigid gold standard, which had limited their ability to respond to economic crises.

The 1980s marked a turning point, with central banks increasingly gaining independence from political interference. This shift aimed to prevent the manipulation of interest rates for short-term political gain, a practice that had often led to boom-and-bust cycles corresponding with election years.

New Zealand pioneered inflation targeting in 1990, with its government requiring the central bank to keep inflation between zero and two percent. This approach quickly spread, with most central banks adopting similar targets, typically around two percent inflation per year.

Interest rates became the primary tool for controlling inflation and economic activity. By adjusting these rates, central banks could influence borrowing and spending throughout the economy. Lower rates encourage investment and consumption, while higher rates cool an overheating economy. This delicate balancing act requires central bankers to anticipate economic trends and act preemptively – not always an easy feat.

Theories of Economic Development

Alongside these changes in monetary policy came new theories of economic development. Justin Yifu Lin, who defected from Taiwan to mainland China before becoming a prominent economist, proposed that successful developing countries combined market orientation with proactive state guidance.

This approach involved identifying industries with comparative advantages and providing targeted support through infrastructure investment and research funding. Lin argued that this strategy was key to the rapid growth of East Asian economies, challenging the notion that a purely hands-off approach was always best for economic development.

Mariana Mazzucato, an economist at University College London, complemented this view by highlighting the crucial role of government-funded "missions" in driving technological innovation. She pointed out that many breakthroughs often attributed to the private sector, such as the internet, actually stemmed from state-led initiatives. This perspective challenges the common narrative that innovation is primarily driven by private enterprise, suggesting a more nuanced view of the relationship between public and private sectors in fostering economic growth.

Global Inequality and Economic Growth

As the global economy grew, so did concerns about inequality. Serbian-born economist Branko Milanović's research on global income distribution revealed a stark picture of uneven growth. His findings showed that between 1980 to 2016, while the global middle class (particularly in emerging economies like China and India) experienced significant income gains, those in the lower-middle income brackets of developed countries saw stagnation or even decline.

Meanwhile, the world's top earners, especially the top one percent, enjoyed spectacular growth in their incomes. This pattern of growth highlighted the complex effects of globalization and technological change on different segments of the global population.

Factors influencing equality include education, union strength, progressive taxation, and the balance between economic growth and returns on capital. Understanding and addressing these factors has become a key challenge for economists and policymakers in the 21st century.

Conclusion: The Ongoing Economic Journey

"The Shortest History of Economics" by Andrew Leigh demonstrates that the human story is one of constant innovation and adaptation. From the agricultural revolution to the digital age, humans have developed new tools and systems to address scarcity and meet our ever-evolving needs.

Key innovations like specialization, money, and trade formed the bedrock of early economic development. The industrial revolution accelerated progress, while introducing new challenges that we continue to grapple with today. Central banks emerged as crucial economic managers, while debates between interventionist and free-market approaches continue to rage, shaping policy and politics alike.

As we look to the future, the lessons of economic history remain relevant. The challenges of inequality, sustainable growth, and technological disruption echo themes that have recurred throughout our economic journey. By understanding this history, we can better navigate the complex economic landscape of the present and prepare for the challenges of tomorrow.

Leigh's work reminds us that economics is not just about numbers and graphs, but about the story of human progress, ingenuity, and the ongoing quest to improve our collective well-being. As we face new global challenges, from climate change to artificial intelligence, the principles and lessons outlined in this book will continue to inform our economic decisions and shape our shared future.

Books like The Shortest History of Economics